Pareto principle (land theory)Pareto pea pods
Left: a land ownership perspective of the Pareto principle, that 80 percent of land tends to be owned by 20 percent of the population. Both phenomenon, supposedly, were observed in the early 1900s by Italian mathematician and engineer-economist Vilfredo Pareto. [6] Right: a production perspective of the Pareto principle, that 20 percent of peas in a garden produce or yield 80 percent of the peas.
In economics, Pareto principle, also known as the “80-20 rule” or “Pareto’s natural law of wealth”, refers to the phenomena that about 80 percent of a country’s wealth tends to be held in about 20 percent of the population. [1]

Formulation
The Pareto principle, according to Jaroslav Sestak, asserts that the statistical character of wealth in a stable economy is modeled by the following power law distribution: [9]

y\approx x^{{-a}}\,

where y is the number of people having an income x or greater than x and a is an exponent that was estimated to be 1.5 applicable to various conditions and nations.

Etymology
The principle is named after French-Italian mathematical engineer and economist Vilfredo Pareto, who first discussed the phenomenon in his 1897 Course of Political Economics. [7]

In his 1902 Socialist Systems, Pareto elaborated on his earlier 1896 outlined wealth distribution principle ideas with the following diagram (see: Pareto social pyramid)—shown with added clarification annotated—and comments: [8]

“The curve of the distribution of wealth in our society, varies little from one era to another. What is called social pyramid is in reality a sort of spinning top, which the following figure gives an idea:
Pareto principle (annotated)
Rich occupying the summit, the poor are at the base. Abcgf the part of the curve we are only well known, thanks to the statistical data. The adef part is only speculative. We have adopted the form indicated by Otto Ammon and which seems to us quite likely that the shape of the curve is not due to chance. It probably depends on the distribution of the physiological and psychological characteristics of men. Moreover, can, in part, relate to the theories of pure economics, that is to say, the choice of men (these choices are specifically related to the physiological and psychological characteristics) and the obstacles encountered in production.

Assuming men arranged in layers according to their wealth, figure abcgfed is the outer form of the social organism. From what we have said this form does not change much, it can be assumed nearly constant on average and for a short time. But the molecules that make up the social aggregate do not remain at rest; individuals get richer, others poorer. So quite extensive are the agitated movements within the social organism, which resembles, in this, a living organism. In the latter, the blood flow is rapidly moving some molecules, the absorption and secretion processes continually change the molecules composing the tissue, while the external shape of the body, such as an adult animal, feels only insignificant changes.

Assuming men arranged in layers according to other characters, such as their intelligence, their ability to study mathematics, their musical talent, poetic, literary, their moral character, etc., it is likely to have curves forms more or less similar to what we just found for the distribution of wealth.”

In 1906, Pareto observed that 80% of the land in Italy was owned by 20% of the population; Pareto is said to have developed or arrived at the principle by observing that 20% of the pea pods in his garden contained or harvested 80% of the peas. [5] In the 1940s, Romanian-born American business-management consultant and engineer Joseph Juran suggested the principle and named it after Pareto, whose work he had become acquainted with during a 1941 visit to General Motors Headquarters. [4]

Thermodynamics
In 2007, American physicist Mark Buchanan discusses the Pareto principle in the context of thermodynamics and his social atom theory. [1]

In 2008, American electrochemical engineer Libb Thims discussed the 1980s “lazy ant study”, which found that ants can be divided into two categories: one consisting of hard workers, the other of inactive or ‘lazy’ ants, and that if the “system” is shattered by separating the two groups from one another, each in turn developed its own subgroups of hard workers and idlers—in other words, a significant percentage of the ‘lazy’ ants suddenly turned into hard working ants—in terms of the mechanical equivalent of heat and the Pareto principle. [2]

In 2011, American chemical engineer James Ferri oversaw a biomolecular engineering student produced video on the Pareto principle in the context of thermodynamics. [3]

Note
The 80-20 rule has since been applied baselessly to a number of non-wealth (land ownership) related scenarios, e.g. that “20% of one’s effort produce 80% of the results”, that “20% of the salespeople produce 80% of the sales”, among others.

References
1. Buchanan, Mark. (2007). The Social Atom: Why the Rich get Richer, Cheaters get Caught, and Your Neighbor Usually Looks Like You (Pareto’s natural law of wealth, pg. 196). Bloomsbury.
2. (a) Thims, Libb. (2008). “On the Mechanical Equivalent of Heat and Occupation” (online), Journal of Human Thermodynamics, 4(1):1-8.
(b) Prigogine, Ilya. (1984). Order Out of Chaos – Man’s New Dialogue with Nature, (pg. xxiv). New York: Bantam Books.
3. (a) Ferri, James K, Kaminski, Ashley (artwork), Wnek, Angela (script), Lavine, Isaac (script). (2011). “Thermodynamics of Life: Wall Street Edition”, YouTube, Oct. 26.
(b) Occupy Wall Street – Wikipedia.
4. Stephens, Kenneth S. and Juran, Joseph M. (2005). Juran, Quality, and a Century of Improvement(§: The Pareto Principle, pg. 72). ASQ Quality Press.
5. Manganelli, Raymond and Hagen, Brian W. (2003). Solving the Corporate Value Enigma: A System to Unlock Shareholder Value (§: Pareto Rule, pg. 221). AMACOM Div American Mgmt Assn.
6. Cott, Megan. (2012). “Understanding the Pareto principle (aka the 80/20 rule)”, Stick Figure Economics, Blogspot.com, Jun 28.
7. (a) Pareto, Vilfredo. (1896). Course of Political Economics (Cours d’Economie Politique), Volume One. University of Lausanne.
(b) Pareto, Vilfredo. (1897). Course of Political Economics (Cours d’Economie Politique), Volume Two. University of Lausanne.
(c) Gligor, Mircea. (2012). "Nonlinear Mechanisms of Generating Power Laws in Socioeconomic Systems", in: Econophysics: Background and Applications in Economics, Finance, and Sociophysics (pg. 55). Academic Press.
8. (a) Pareto, Vilfredo. (1902). The Socialist Systems, Volume 1 (Les Systéms Socialistes, Volume 1) (diagram, pgs. 6-7). V. Giard & E. Briére.
(b) Pareto, Vilfredo. (1902). The Socialist Systems, Volume 2 (Les Systéms Socialistes, Volume 2). V. Giard & E. Briére.
9. Sestak, Jaroslav. (2005). Science of Heat and Thermophysical Studies: a Generalized Approach to Thermal Analysis (§8: Thermodynamics, Econophysics, Ecosystems and Societal Behavior, pgs. 230-; 8.3: Thermodynamic Laws Versus Human Feelings, pgs. 236-42; Pareto principle, pg. 230-31). Gulf Professional Publishing.

Further reading
● Clementi, Fabio and Gallegati, Mauro. (2005). “Pareto’s Law of Income Distribution: Evidence for Germany, the United Kingdom, and the United States.” In: Econophysics of Wealth Distributions (edited by Arnab. Chatterjee, Bikas K. Chakrabarti, Sudhakar. Yarlagadda) (pgs. 3-). Springer.

External links
Pareto principle – Wikipedia.

TDics icon ns